Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

Teh supposed "breakdown of trade" in teh Dark Ages

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • Teh supposed "breakdown of trade" in teh Dark Ages

    For more than fifty years, the history of the Middle Ages has been dominated by the ‘Pirenne Thesis’, with which a great historian sought to explain the collapse of the ancient world and the establishment of the medieval economic order in Charlemagne’s Europe. Great historians, like all great men, cast long shadows. Henri Pirenne, the venerable Belgian medievalist behind the Pirenne Thesis, has had an enormous influence on the study of European medieval history and has provoked one of the most exciting debates in the field. Following his release from a German prison camp in the 1920s, Pirenne began work on a series of papers and lectures that culminated in 1935 in the publication of his revolutionary book, Mohammed and Charlemagne, in which his thesis was proposed.
    Pirenne constructed his thesis against a background of intellectual stagnation in medieval history. Since the Renaissance, historians had stressed the ‘Gothic bleakness’ of the Dark Ages, and focused on the apparently cataclysmic impact of the Germanic ‘invasions’ on the rich civilization of Rome early in the fifth century. As a result, historians of the ancient world terminated their studies with the fifth century, while medievalists began theirs with the Germanic inundation of Western Europe from that time on, a schism that to some extent still remains. Pirenne was one of the first historians to stand back from these entrenched views of the past and to consider the interactions between the ancient and medieval worlds. The Pirenne thesis upset the traditional historical conceptions regarding the location of the boundary between these two worlds, and has formed the basis of subsequent discussion on the topic. According to Pirenne, it was not the Germanic invasions that led to the fall of the Roman way of life; the migrant tribes of the fourth to sixth centuries preserved what political, economic and social conditions they could and did not deliberately destroy classical civilization. The ancient world only ended after the extremely successful, and unexpected, Arab conquests of the seventh and eighth centuries had swept around the perimeter of the Mediterranean, effectively overthrowing the ‘Roman’ mastery of the sea lanes. This, Pirenne argued, destroyed the essential and characteristic lifeblood of the Roman Empire – its unity and coherence. For centuries, the Mare Nostrum of the Romans had held firm the great imperial structure; over its waters had passed trade and commerce, the Roman military and naval might, and the vital exchange of ideas. As a result of the Arab gains, the remnants of the Western Empire were separated from the Eastern Empire of Byzantium. Political, cultural and economic exchange ended. Except for the most tenuous of ties between Constantinople and a few Italian ports, where the Byzantine fleet afforded some protection, Christian ports were cut off from one another, and could not maintain communication or maritime trade; the Muslims had rolled down an iron curtain between the East and West that remained down until the eleventh century. The central idea of the thesis is that these dramatic changes in the Mediterranean isolated the Merovingian Franks in north-west Europe and caused the gradual rise of the Carolingians, who were economically more remote. The isolation of Italy compelled the Pope to ally himself with the aspiring Carolingian dynasty in the late eight century, and ultimately led to the coronation of Charlemagne as emperor. Mohammed had made possible Charlemagne. The most famous passage from Mohammed and Charlemagne concludes:
    It is therefore strictly correct to say that without Mohammed Charlemagne would have been inconceivable. In the seventh century the ancient Roman Empire had actually become and Empire of the East; the Empire of Charles was an Empire of the West … The Carolingian Empire, or rather, the Empire of Charlemagne, was the scaffolding of the Middle Ages.
    The West, which had always drawn upon the superior economic resources of the East, reverted to an agrarian economy, “an economy of no outlets”. Urban life collapsed, the middle class disappeared and political power became focused on land holdings and in the hands of the Church. Finally, it was Charlemagne who decisively altered the situation, standing astride the gap between a static closed economy and an emergent, fluent one.
    On the whole historians are wary, perhaps too wary, of broad generalizing themes, but Pirenne’s thesis demanded particular attention. His brilliant generalizations have attracted an enormous volume of critical comment by historians, numismatists and archaeologists.
    Ferdinand Vercauteren (1930s), a member of the old school of historical thought and a student of Pirenne, published a paper on the role of merchants in Western Europe. He supports Pirenne’s view in that, by the ninth century, a pan-European economy had established itself in European civilization. The merchants, who had until the ninth century been known as negociators, began to be referred to as mercators, men of the mercatum or market. These merchants were itinerant, and in an age in which traffic was minimal and regional differences sharp, men from outside could have a sharp psychological resonance. That they traveled through such widely different regions, from Byzantium to England, Muslim Spain to the Slav border lands, makes it reasonable to attach some cultural significance to the merchant community. Conspicuous in Vercauteren’s work is that he acknowledges the existence of commercial links between East and West, and in this sense, it is the first noteworthy revision of the Pirenne thesis.
    Marcel Mauss and Karl Polanyi, an anthropologist and an economist respectively, serve to demonstrate how closely history is related to other fields. Though perhaps unaware of the Pirenne thesis, their works put it, and economic history in general, into an entirely new perspective. In his particularly insightful work entitled The Gift, Mauss examined the nature of gift-giving in different societies across the world. The foundation of a particular form of circulation of goods and services is the social obligation to give, to receive, and to repay. Mauss termed such a condition “the formality of the potlatch”, after a custom in Melanesian societies in which social status, power and net worth are established not by the amount of wealth that one owns, but by the amount that is freely distributed. Such an economic structure requires counter-gift as well, lest it collapse. A gift not yet repaid debases the man who accepted it; failure to offer counter-gifts is equivalent to a declaration of war. This informal, yet highly structured, framework of circulation can be summed up by the following Maori philosophy:
    You give me a gift; I give it to another. He gives me a return gift which I am obliged, by the spirit of the gift, to give to you.
    While one might argue that a particular custom of certain Pacific islanders is irrelevant in the context of medieval European society, similar behavior can in fact be found. For instance, the Germanic custom of feasting can be understood in terms of “the formality of the potlatch”.
    Polanyi’s argument is that in modern market economies the needs of the market determine social behavior, whereas in pre-industrial and primitive economies the needs of society determined economic behavior. Drawing heavily on Mauss and other anthropologists such as Malinowski and Thurnwald, he introduced the concepts of reciprocity and redistribution. According to Polanyi, economy is an instituted process – the ‘changing of hands’ of goods and services is enmeshed in institutions, both economic and non-economic. For a framework for the circulation of goods and services to arise, an economy needs to be integrated, or institutionalized. This can be brought about in three ways – reciprocity, redistribution and exchange. The subject of economics usually deals exclusively with exchange economies; this is the type of economy to which economists refer when they use the word ‘economy’. An exchange economy is instituted by barter and commerce, markets and money. In the period under study, however, the other two types of economies, namely, reciprocative and redistributive economies, have a previously unseen significance, and must be discussed in further detail.
    A reciprocative economy is based on mutual interactions between socially and legally symmetric groups, such as clans, families or individuals. Circulation of goods and services is brought about primarily by gift, though pillage and tribute are also important. In a reciprocal economy, each individual produces what he or she is best suited to produce. The produce is shared with the community, and this is reciprocated by the other individuals of the community. The motivation to produce and share is not personal profit but rather, as Mauss theorized, fear of social contempt, ostracism and loss of prestige.
    An economy in which goods and services flow towards a center, and then outwards to different spatial and social locations, is called a redistributive economy. Commodities change hands by redistribution. Taxation and subsequent public spending is an important example of such redistribution, as is royally administered material exchange between estates.
    One of the weaknesses in the works of Pirenne and Vercauteren is that their economic interpretations were set in essentially traditional moulds; notions of reciprocity and redistribution never occurred to them This traditional approach remained intact until 1959 when Philip Grierson offered a new interpretation of the economic implications of Pirenne’s thesis. In his celebrated paper Commerce in the Dark Ages: A critique of the evidence, Grierson declared:
    All that we know of the social conditions of the time suggests that the alternatives to trade were more important that trade itself: the onus probandi rests on those who believe the contrary to have been the case.
    Grierson drew attention to the social importance of exchange, in particular to the concept of gift exchange derived from Mauss. The main thrust of Grierson’s essay was to emphasize that in the Dark Ages the social dimension of exchange was probably more important that the economic one. In other words, the economic matrix was entirely different from that of the Roman period, which was based on firm market principles.
    Georges Duby wrote in the 1960s on the nature of European economies. Clearly influenced by Polanyi and Grierson, he argued that the economies of the ancient Germanic societies were almost purely reciprocative and redistributive. The distribution of gifts, the hosting of feasts and the offering of brides served the purposes of circulation of goods and services as well as the maintenance of social structures. Pillage too played an important role. Armies and war-bands would raid enemy settlements and seize such items as ornaments, weapons, cattle and even people. Pillage and counter-pillage functioned much as gift and counter-gift did. Peace between two groups could be defined as the prospect of the exchange of gifts. Redistribution too was manifested by pillage, followed by the distribution of the spoils by the warlord to the members of the clan. Arts and crafts, especially gold-working, were supported by the ‘kings’, who required that their gifts and plunder be fashioned into coherent forms for public display of their wealth. Tribute was a form of gift, made by the weak to the strong in order to maintain peace. In pagan areas, the dead, who were buried with elaborate burial items and rituals, constituted an important class of consumers.
    In the Roman world, by contrast, there existed an advanced exchange economy. Money, in the form of coins, was in wide circulation, and supported markets and commerce. Large volumes of commodities were traded internationally, and merchant classes, such as the Syrians and the Jews, assumed prominence as maritime traders and businessmen. Luxury items such as spices, ivory, silk, wine, papyrus and oil were imported from the East for the elites. Within the empire, cereals, wine, pottery, slaves, wool and textiles were traded among the various provinces.
    Peter Spufford (1980s), a numismatist, explained in great depth, on the authority of archaeological and literary evidence, the system of coinage in and after the Roman Empire. Gold was plentiful in the empire. The solidus, a gold coin, was the unit of currency in terms of which prices were expressed. In addition to the solidus, coins of lower denominations were also used, such as the gold semissis and tremissis (triens), the copper nummus, and the silver miliarenses. Such coins were essential for day-to-day expenses of city dwellers and to commercial traders, and were used by the large urban population of the empire, and by merchants.
    Following the collapse of the Roman Empire, the European economy witnessed a regression. Wave after wave of plague decimated the population of Southern Europe. Urban life dwindled, and towns remained as nothing more than forts and ecclesiastical centers. Political organization disintegrated, and the lack of a strong central authority resulted in the collapse of a system of coinage. Public expenditure ceased – there was no army or civil service requiring payment in gold, no state transportation system to maintain, nor were there bulk purchases of food for free distribution. Peasants subsisted upon land through the system of economic exploitation called seignorialism. Coinage declined rapidly; gold was steadily replaced by silver, and the silver declined in quality over time.
    Spufford and Duby agree in that, contrary to the Pirenne Thesis, the dwindling of the Roman market economy is no longer considered to be as abrupt as was once thought, but rather, as gradual and prolonged a process as the disintegration of Roman power and the disappearance of the Roman senatorial aristocracy. Furthermore, the decline of the Roman economy and way of life began long before the Arab conquests, and the general consensus is that Pirenne exaggerated the impact of Islam on the collapse of the European economy.
    In the 1980s, Richard Hodges and David Whitehouse published a critique of Pirenne’s thesis based on archaeological evidence. Building on the ideas of Grierson, they dismissed Pirenne’s notion of a totally closed economy, and instead supported the view that a modified economy did exist in Europe. They described the nature of the redistributive economy, in which the elites of the society fostered administered markets of small artisan classes and controlled the movement of valuable commodities. Trade partnerships with other chiefdoms enhanced political position, and therefore, administered bilateral trade expanded. To regulate such trade, it was confined to specific trading posts, such as Quentovic and Dorestad on the North Sea. Commercial trade did not completely disappear either. In the North Sea and Rhine valley, it expanded under the industrious Frisians. Peasant markets and fairs constituted a primitive rural market economy. On the whole, however, the exchange economy was insignificant. Commerce, credit, and regular exchange were no longer needed for the maintenance of the social fabric. The whole of society was in a state of dependence on the owners of the soil and the dispensers of justice. Economic independence had reached its lowest point, and in this regard, the Pirenne thesis remains unchallenged.
    James Campbell, in his publication The Anglo-Saxons (1982), cautioned against being too optimistic regarding the extent of commerce in this period. He argued that the development of an international trading network in the Dark Ages does not necessarily suggest the existence of a true market economy, but rather a regulated, royally administered form of redistributive trade. This hypothesis is corroborated by archaeological, numismatic and literary evidence gathered at Hamwih, a mid-Saxon English port of the early eighth century. At Hamwih, merchants, who paid heavy tolls in exchange for royal protection, purchased goods such as livestock and other commodities which kings collected from their subjects and defeated enemies. Enormous quantities of animal remains and items of precious metals have been found, in addition to large volumes of locally minted coins. Campbell points out:
    …the gathering of [such commodities] was more likely to have been achieved by the exercise of royal power and the collection of royal dues than via the mechanism of a formal market network which probably did not exist.
    Traders would pay for these goods in kind, selling similar items like agricultural produce and booty from other kingdoms. Thus, we can see that international exchange of goods occurred within the framework of a modified redistributive economy in which merchants and traders played the role of intermediaries in the chain of redistribution.
    Pirenne viewed the reign of Charlemagne as the point of inflexion of Europe’s economic graph. He asserted that it was under the reign of Charlemagne that Europe began its gradual ascent out of the economic abyss of the dark ages. The completely isolated manorial “economy of no outlets” gradually gave way to a commercial economic setup. Duby agreed:
    …from this point of view, the rise of Carolingian power marked a decisive phase in the economic history of Europe.
    Spufford, too, supported the view of a resurgent Europe. Political structures had reached the level of maturity necessary for the establishment of a framework for monetary circulation. The introduction of the silver denier injected a fresh vitality into the stagnant economy and facilitated the linkage of trade with markets. The denier gave North Sea trade a fresh impetus, and facilitated an increase in public spending. Spufford observed that money became more readily available. Furthermore, Carolingian military campaigns, particularly those in Slavic areas, resulted in the capture of thousands of slaves for export. Consequently, Europe’s trade deficit was erased, at least temporarily, by the inflow of Arab and Byzantine gold into the economy.
    Pierre Riché (1980s) also cited the revival of coinage by the Carolingians as the most important factor in the economic revival of Europe. The Carolingians passed legislation aimed at bringing about universal acceptance of coinage. At the council of Frankfurt in 794, Charlemagne passed the following resolution:
    As regards denarii, know that we have decreed that everywhere, in every town and every trading place, the new denarii are also to be legal tender and to be accepted by everybody. And if they bear the monogram of our name and are of pure silver, should anyone reject them… he is to pay fifteen solidi.
    The proliferation of the denier sparked a revival of local and regional trade. Coinage began to be used for trade, wages, to redeem obligations in kind, to collect duty from merchants, and to levy the tribute demanded by the Scandinavians. Even when exchange was conducted without coins, prices were expressed in terms of the denier. Riché concludes:
    Carolingian monetary reforms resulted in a vast monometallic ‘silver zone’ that prevailed across Europe until the reemergence of gold coinage in the thirteenth century.
    THEY!!111 OMG WTF LOL LET DA NOMADS AND TEH S3D3NTARY PEOPLA BOTH MAEK BITER AXP3REINCES
    AND TEH GRAAT SINS OF THERE [DOCTRINAL] INOVATIONS BQU3ATH3D SMAL
    AND!!1!11!!! LOL JUST IN CAES A DISPUTANT CALS U 2 DISPUT3 ABOUT THEYRE CLAMES
    DO NOT THAN DISPUT3 ON THEM 3XCAPT BY WAY OF AN 3XTARNAL DISPUTA!!!!11!! WTF

  • #2
    [q] Charlemagne was crowned Emperor on Christmas Day, 800, by which time he had reached almost unimaginable success. After his coronation, he inclined more towards the image of patron of the Western Church; at the same time, he propagated a new spiritualism from his courts. This was the beginning of the Carolingian renaissance, which continued into the reign of Charlemagne’s son and successor, Louis the Pious. In the Aachen synods of 816 and 817, new monastic codes were promulgated, accelerating the cultural revolution by calling for the construction of new monasteries and churches and the renovation of existing ones. At the same time, it created the need for new art forms, be they church ornaments or sacred texts.
    This phase of imperial ordered was dramatically terminated in 828, when Louis granted his youngest son Charles a share of the empire, precipitating civil war. At around the same time, Scandinavian raiders began to appear regularly. These events threw Western Europe into a state of turmoil, and Charlemagne’s imperial and cultural legacies were fatally threatened.
    The Carolingian renaissance required large sums of money to fund the grand projects envisaged by Charlemagne and Louis and their clerical advisers. Initially, they were probably financed by the internal wealth of the empire, such as revenues from imperial estates and even church treasures. It is doubtful whether this could be sustained. Pirenne proposed, rather obliquely, that Islamic silver compensated for the apparent shortfall. On the basis of the results of early archaeological excavations at Dorestad and Haithabu, Pirenne proposed that, following the closure of Mediterranean trade, Arab dirhams followed a circuitous route from Baghdad to Dorestad, passing through the hands of the Khazarians and Bulghars, Scandinavian slave traders in Russia, Baltic Scandinavians, for whom Haithabu was the principle trading emporium, and Frisian merchants before arriving in the Empire. The symbolic link between Mohammed and Charlemagne was formed in the Russian steppes. Those along the chain of trade profited from the commerce, but were nevertheless in a very tenuous position – the entire system would be threatened if a crisis occurred in one link of the chain.
    Pirenne perceived the weakening of the Oriental link in the 820s, possibly due to a shortage of silver in the Arab world or the political turmoil in Baghdad after Caliph Haroun al-Raschid’s death, as the beginning of the end of the Carolingian empire. As a result, the Scandinavian merchants, and pirates, who profited from the pre-existing arrangement, saw their supply of silver from the East evaporate, and turned to Western Europe to satisfy their desire for silver. The ensuing Viking raids on continental Europe had a devastating impact on the Carolingian political order and precipitated its collapse.
    The notion that the Vikings had a devastating impact on the rest of Europe found early takers. In The Church in Early Irish Society (1966), Kathleen Hughes corroborated Pirenne’s view regarding the ‘chronology of terror’. After 830, Ireland was rarely ever without Vikings. They began to arrive in increasing numbers and conducted ferocious raids, especially on the Irish churches and monasteries, whose wealth was by then famous in Scandinavia. In the 840s, the Vikings began to build fortresses and colonies, such as Dublin. From these fortified camps, the Vikings could attack neighboring regions with impunity. The effects of these attacks were physically and mentally devastating. In addition to the destruction of church property, the plunder of sacred relics left the people bewildered – the supernatural immunity of the saints appeared useless, accepted standards were worthless, and society was thrown into anarchy.
    Michel Rouche (1960s) invoked archaeological data in his discussion of the Viking assaults on the towns of Northern Gaul. He shared Pirenne’s view of a movement towards urbanization and the establishment of market towns. To facilitate their expansion, local prelates sought and obtained permission to pull down the old Roman fortifications around the towns, and so by the middle of the ninth century the towns in Gaul were rich and poorly defended, and constituted inviting targets to Viking raiders. The initial response to the Viking menace was counter-attack, but the Vikings had established themselves in fortified camps on river islands. As a result, by the tenth century many urban centers had rebuilt their fortifications. The rebuilding was undertaken not at central behest but rather by local counts. Rouche applied this fact to his thesis that the Vikings, with their network of fortified camps scattered throughout a peaceful kingdom that had forgotten Roman military order, caused the break-up of central political power. Smaller, locally built, fortified units of authority replaced central control over the countryside. In this respect, Rouche concedes to Pirenne’s view that the Viking raids led to the collapse of the Carolingian empire, but instead of a gradually evolving feudal system, Rouche hypothesizes that the feudal system was established rather rapidly, following the Viking assaults.
    P.H. Sawyer (1960s) examined the Scandinavian economic infrastructure and its importance to Western Europe. He explained that the driving force behind Scandinavian activity was the acquisition of silver. From around the 700s to the 830s, the Scandinavians satisfied their desire for silver by trading with the Muslims of Central Asia. The Swedes, expanding along the Volga into modern Russia, plundered and enslaved the local Slavic people. They sold these slaves, and native Scandinavian products such as fur and amber, to Khazar and Transoxonian (from Samarkand, Tashkent and Merv) merchants in return for Arabic silver. The transactions took place in the region of the lower Don and also of the Oxus across Bulghar. This silver found its way to Birka in Sweden, Haithabu in Denmark and Kaupang in Norway, where it was exchanged with Frisian merchants for commodities such as pottery, glass and weapons. Sawyer uses an apt quote of Grierson to pursue his point:
    The Vikings were important in European commerce because by the accumulation of treasure they naturally encouraged enterprising merchants to attempt to relieve them of it by offering goods in exchange.
    This trading activity also supported pirates who plied the Baltic and North Seas; that piracy thrived indicates that there was loot to plunder. The interruption of the flow of silver into Scandinavia, indicated by the fact that coin hoards have been found with coins dating from before 820 and after 890, and not in between, had serious consequences. Scandinavian pirates were forced to rely on Europe for their silver, and the silver reaching Scandinavia thereafter was largely loot, tribute (danegeld), or mercenary fees (heregeld).
    Sawyer also highlighted the dangers of relying too heavily on literary sources at the expense of archaeological and place-name evidence. Contemporary literature was written by churchmen, who, as the primary victims of the Viking raids, were hardly unbiased in their writings. Sawyer argued that they regularly exaggerated the sizes of the attacking forces, in an attempt to justify defeat or highlight victories. For instance, it is very possible that many, if not all, Viking raids on monasteries and churches were little more than violent acts of robbery, and he also pointed out that armies of more than a thousand men, such as those described by some chronicles, would have faced problems of supply, discipline and mobility, and would not have been nearly as successful as smaller, compact war bands. He believed that archaeological and linguistic evidence should serve to corroborate literary evidence. Rather than treating them as a welcome check on literary sources, apparent discrepancies brought up by archaeology and linguistics are too often explained away. The deeply rooted conviction that the Vikings came in large armies and spread little but desolation with unparalleled savagery seriously handicaps attempts to determine the true nature and extent of the Viking menace. This view raises doubts about Hughes’ and Pirenne’s conclusions regarding the extent to which the Vikings were able to influence events in Western Europe. In Sawyer’s words:
    …once the prejudices and exaggerations of the primary sources are recognized, the raids can be seen not as an unprecedented and inexplicable cataclysm, but as an extension of normal Dark Age activity, made possible and profitable by special circumstances.
    Recent archaeological excavations have thrown light on the Viking presence in England. In 1978, Robert Hall analyzed the data obtained by these excavations to study the dark-age history of York. Originally a Roman fortress town, York passed to the Britons before being occupied by the Anglians in the eighth century. There is evidence of commercial activity in the area – York housed a Frisian merchant community and served as an international port. In the mid ninth century, it was captured by the Vikings, and came to be known as Jorvik. Under the Vikings, York saw the reconstruction of its fortifications, and it became the capital of a Scandinavian state in England known as the Danelaw. The Vikings also built a market area physically separate from the old town. Hall’s work suggests that the Vikings were settlers and builders and not solely bloodthirsty warriors.
    Campbell, however, argued against being overzealous in the revision of the scale of Viking attacks. He disputed Sawyer’s view of Vikings as being primarily traders and settlers rather than warriors. Owing to the lack of definite evidence for settlement prior to 850, Campbell concluded that, at least initially, the Vikings were in fact predatory warbands of the type familiar in Germanic literature. He also drew attention to the strange fact that wholly independent contemporary literary sources in different parts of Europe give the same sort of figures regarding the scale of the Viking attacks. In addition, in the Danelaw, the episcopal lists of every diocese except York and Lindisfarne are interrupted for decades. Three bishoprics disappeared altogether. Medieval bishoprics were durable institutions, which seldom, if ever, disappeared because of mere ‘decay’. Such disruptions in the history of the Danelaw bishoprics suggest that the effect of the Viking invasions were very serious indeed. The armies of the 860s and 870s, as concentrations of warbands from all over Europe under ambitious royal leadership, could very well have numbered in the thousands.
    Spufford applied Rouche’s idea of the rise of local authority to the fragmentation of minting. Following the Scandinavian attacks, royal control over minting dissipated to the counts, causing coinage, which had succeeded largely due to royal efforts, to suffer. In addition, the trade balance between East and West, which for a while had been in favor of the West, swung back in favor of the East following the cessation of imperial conquests and the subsequent reduction in the number of slaves available or export. As a result, silver flowed out of Europe, and mining activities were not sufficient enough to compensate for the loss. Silver supplies further decreased as a consequence of extraordinary diversion of silver into church treasuries, and the Viking invasions. More important, perhaps, was that the velocity of circulation of coins decreased. The destruction of market towns and the sack of seaports devastated the embryonic market economy. This economic dark-age envisaged by Spufford continued to the end of the tenth century, until the revival of coinage under the Ottonians of Saxony following the opening of the Harz mines in the 980s. Despite the immediate setback to the economy, however, Spufford viewed the Vikings as economic liberators in some sense, in that they forced Europe to think small – the break-up of the vast Carolingian landed estates ultimately proved beneficial in that it increased agricultural efficiency. The Vikings also liberated treasure that had been locked in church hoards, removed from general circulation.
    Campbell also shed light on the long-term economic benefits precipitated by the Vikings, the most important being the establishment of the burghal hidage. Despite the immediate setback to trade in England, the Viking presence had a positive effect on commerce in that the creation of Alfred’s burhs, initially planned for defense, eventually became important market centers. The establishment of later burhs provided for the setting up of markets and mints, and grew to become important sources of revenue for the king and the episcopacy. They also became lucrative as trading centers for their inhabitants. Their creation gave an impetus to urbanization and commercialization of Southern England. Laws of tenth century kings demanded that trade take place in the towns, and they developed into places of permanent habitation and vibrant trade. A charter from the 920s stipulates that one in every nine ‘agrarian soldiers’ was to live in the town and construct dwellings for himself and eight others, who were to keep him supplied. Later, when many such burhs became mints, the inhabitants paid a profitable rent to the king. The burh was thus an important source of wealth and power to the king. These centers, set up in the wake of devastating Viking attacks, supplied not only the scaffolding for the Anglo-Saxon administrative and military structure, but also became extremely lucrative trading centers for their inhabitants and the king, and for the economy at large.
    Hodges and Whitehouse argued against Pirenne’s belief in the gradual evolution of North Sea trade, and proposed instead, on the authority of recent excavations at Dorestad, a sudden and massive economic expansion and a correspondingly explosive increase in maritime trading activity. They also challenged Pirenne’s assertion that there was a gradual evolution of a ‘feudal system’, and offer large-scale rebuilding as an alternate explanation for the development of the market in rural areas.
    Furthermore, contrary to Pirenne’s notion of a closed curtain drawn across the Mediterranean, they highlighted the existence of nominal contacts between the Abbasid caliphate and the Carolingians, manifested in the form of embassies and the exchange of gifts. However, spiritual divisions and the opposition to maritime links formed by the formidable Byzantine navy deterred any substantial level of diplomacy between the two powers.
    Hodges and Whitehouse, along with other historians like Sawyer, insisted upon other factors in addition to the Viking invasions as precipitating the collapse of the great Carolingian administrative machinery. For example, the fact that imperial grants to the church increased dramatically, causing the amount of land under the church to triple in area between 750 and 825, caused the alienation of the Frankish nobility who had grown accustomed to being enriched with church lands. By removing the critical role of Islam, Hodges and Whitehouse demolished one of the planks upon which the Pirenne thesis rested.
    The modern perspective on history is that change is extremely gradual, and that it does not necessarily occur in significant steps and processes. Henri Pirenne, though he asked all the right questions, erred in that he answered them by attempting to identify these non-existent significant steps. Pirenne’s thesis is too well-structured, smooth and chronological, and, while appealing to contemporary intuitions, is contrary to the modern acceptance of the fact that history is an extremely messy, local, and specific process. He also suffered the disadvantage of working in a time when other forms of evidence were not very abundant. Later discoveries in the fields of archaeology, linguistics and numismatics have played major roles in detecting flaws in the Pirenne thesis, as have advances in other areas of human knowledge and their effects on the study of history.
    Nevertheless, Henri Pirenne was a visionary. His work compels every scholar to wrestle with the concepts of his grand thesis because within their framework rests a truer understanding of the middle ages. It is also noteworthy that after decades of scrutiny and revision, the basic skeleton of the Pirenne theory is still considered valid.


    Sorry! The administrator has specified that users can only post one message every 30 seconds.
    THEY!!111 OMG WTF LOL LET DA NOMADS AND TEH S3D3NTARY PEOPLA BOTH MAEK BITER AXP3REINCES
    AND TEH GRAAT SINS OF THERE [DOCTRINAL] INOVATIONS BQU3ATH3D SMAL
    AND!!1!11!!! LOL JUST IN CAES A DISPUTANT CALS U 2 DISPUT3 ABOUT THEYRE CLAMES
    DO NOT THAN DISPUT3 ON THEM 3XCAPT BY WAY OF AN 3XTARNAL DISPUTA!!!!11!! WTF

    Comment


    • #3
      That's completely unreadable, sorry.

      Comment


      • #4
        tl(and unreadable)dr
        USA! USA! USA! USA! USA! USA! USA! USA! USA! USA!
        The video may avatar is from

        Comment


        • #5
          That's exactly what the professor said
          THEY!!111 OMG WTF LOL LET DA NOMADS AND TEH S3D3NTARY PEOPLA BOTH MAEK BITER AXP3REINCES
          AND TEH GRAAT SINS OF THERE [DOCTRINAL] INOVATIONS BQU3ATH3D SMAL
          AND!!1!11!!! LOL JUST IN CAES A DISPUTANT CALS U 2 DISPUT3 ABOUT THEYRE CLAMES
          DO NOT THAN DISPUT3 ON THEM 3XCAPT BY WAY OF AN 3XTARNAL DISPUTA!!!!11!! WTF

          Comment


          • #6
            Could you post a longer version with less paragraph breaks and without the bolding of the salient points please? Lose your tidy little summary too, if possible.

            Comment


            • #7
              tldr

              And I actually tried.
              KH FOR OWNER!
              ASHER FOR CEO!!
              GUYNEMER FOR OT MOD!!!

              Comment


              • #8
                Originally posted by LordShiva
                That's exactly what the professor said
                So why did you foist it on us?
                Lime roots and treachery!
                "Eventually you're left with a bunch of unmemorable posters like Cyclotron, pretending that they actually know anything about who they're debating pointless crap with." - Drake Tungsten

                Comment


                • #9
                  I was inspired by Cali's little brother, and I got a +4 for it
                  THEY!!111 OMG WTF LOL LET DA NOMADS AND TEH S3D3NTARY PEOPLA BOTH MAEK BITER AXP3REINCES
                  AND TEH GRAAT SINS OF THERE [DOCTRINAL] INOVATIONS BQU3ATH3D SMAL
                  AND!!1!11!!! LOL JUST IN CAES A DISPUTANT CALS U 2 DISPUT3 ABOUT THEYRE CLAMES
                  DO NOT THAN DISPUT3 ON THEM 3XCAPT BY WAY OF AN 3XTARNAL DISPUTA!!!!11!! WTF

                  Comment


                  • #10
                    This trading activity also supported pirates who plied the Baltic and North Seas; that piracy thrived indicates that there was loot to plunder. The interruption of the flow of silver into Scandinavia, indicated by the fact that coin hoards have been found with coins dating from before 820 and after 890, and not in between, had serious consequences. Scandinavian pirates were forced to rely on Europe for their silver, and the silver reaching Scandinavia thereafter was largely loot, tribute (danegeld), or mercenary fees (heregeld).
                    Sawyer also highlighted the dangers of relying too heavily on literary sources at the expense of archaeological and place-name evidence. Contemporary literature was written by churchmen, who, as the primary victims of the Viking raids, were hardly unbiased in their writings. Sawyer argued that they regularly exaggerated the sizes of the attacking forces, in an attempt to justify defeat or highlight victories. For instance, it is very possible that many, if not all, Viking raids on monasteries and churches were little more than violent acts of robbery, and he also pointed out that armies of more than a thousand men, such as those described by some chronicles, would have faced problems of supply, discipline and mobility, and would not have been nearly as successful as smaller, compact war bands. He believed that archaeological and linguistic evidence should serve to corroborate literary evidence. Rather than treating them as a welcome check on literary sources, apparent discrepancies brought up by archaeology and linguistics are too often explained away. The deeply rooted conviction that the Vikings came in large armies and spread little but desolation with unparalleled savagery seriously handicaps attempts to determine the true nature and extent of the Viking menace. This view raises doubts about Hughes’ and Pirenne’s conclusions regarding the extent to which the Vikings were able to influence events in Western Europe. In Sawyer’s words:
                    …once the prejudices and exaggerations of the primary sources are recognized, the raids can be seen not as an unprecedented and inexplicable cataclysm, but as an extension of normal Dark Age activity, made possible and profitable by special circumstances.
                    What a load of bull****. 820-890 saw the great period of Viking conquest on the British Isles, with kingdoms set up in York, Dublin and Man/Orkney. It's the era of Ivar the Boneless. You don't achieve that level of conquest with a few piddling little gangs of robbing yobbos.
                    The genesis of the "evil Finn" concept- Evil, evil Finland

                    Comment


                    • #11
                      That trade broke down in 'the Dark Ages' isn't true- the patterns and routes of trade shifted slightly.

                      Byzantium was still receiving fur and amber and beeswax amongst other things from the Baltic, and spices and silk through the Caliphate.

                      Anglo-Saxon England had contacts (however sporadic) with the world of Islamand the Baltic - Offa's 'Arabic' coinage shows this, and an Anglo-Saxon burial site in Norfolk ( I think...) revealed the skull of a young African girl slave. Tallow, furs and timber came from the north, along with walrus ivory and narwhal tusks.

                      Viking burial sites in Scandinavia reveal contacts with Baghdad, the Caucasus and further afield- a bronze seated Buddha being found in one in Helgo in Lake Malaren.


                      The Viking Cuerdale Hoard:

                      The Cuerdale hoard contains over 7,000 coins. Between them they demonstrate very clearly the international scale of Viking activity, as well as providing evidence for the dating of the hoard. Not surprisingly, most of the coins come from England, both official Anglo-Saxon issues (about 1,000) and coins of the Danelaw (about 5,000). However, the hoard also contained about 1,000 Frankish coins, a handful of early Scandinavian coins, about 50 Kufic dirhams from all over the Islamic world, a few imitations of Kufic coins from eastern Europe, and a single Byzantine coin.
                      The best of the BBC, with the latest news and sport headlines, weather, TV & radio highlights and much more from across the whole of BBC Online


                      The Byzantine hexagram of Heraclius:
                      Attached Files
                      Vive la liberte. Noor Inayat Khan, Dachau.

                      ...patriotism is not enough. I must have no hatred or bitterness towards anyone. Edith Cavell, 1915

                      Comment


                      • #12
                        "For more than fifty years, the history of the Middle Ages has been dominated by the ‘Pirenne Thesis’, "

                        er no. Ive read economic histories challenging Pirenne, and counter revisionists attempting to resuscitate Pirenne, for over 20 years.

                        After a distortion like that, I didnt read the rest of this long article.
                        "A person cannot approach the divine by reaching beyond the human. To become human, is what this individual person, has been created for.” Martin Buber

                        Comment


                        • #13
                          Originally posted by Drake Tungsten
                          tldr

                          And I actually tried.
                          Same for me.
                          Christianity: The belief that a cosmic Jewish Zombie who was his own father can make you live forever if you symbolically eat his flesh and telepathically tell him you accept him as your master, so he can remove an evil force from your soul that is present in humanity because a rib-woman was convinced by a talking snake to eat from a magical tree...

                          Comment


                          • #14
                            Originally posted by lord of the mark
                            "For more than fifty years, the history of the Middle Ages has been dominated by the ‘Pirenne Thesis’, "

                            er no. Ive read economic histories challenging Pirenne, and counter revisionists attempting to resuscitate Pirenne, for over 20 years.
                            Pirenne published in 1922-23.

                            Over 50 years since then = 1974.

                            Over 20 years since then = 1990s and 2000s.

                            THEY!!111 OMG WTF LOL LET DA NOMADS AND TEH S3D3NTARY PEOPLA BOTH MAEK BITER AXP3REINCES
                            AND TEH GRAAT SINS OF THERE [DOCTRINAL] INOVATIONS BQU3ATH3D SMAL
                            AND!!1!11!!! LOL JUST IN CAES A DISPUTANT CALS U 2 DISPUT3 ABOUT THEYRE CLAMES
                            DO NOT THAN DISPUT3 ON THEM 3XCAPT BY WAY OF AN 3XTARNAL DISPUTA!!!!11!! WTF

                            Comment


                            • #15
                              Originally posted by LordShiva


                              Pirenne published in 1922-23.

                              Over 50 years since then = 1974.

                              Over 20 years since then = 1990s and 2000s.

                              and why, pray tell, are you posting something over thirty years old, and in full no less?

                              BTW, IIRC many of the challenges to Pirenne were written before 1974.
                              "A person cannot approach the divine by reaching beyond the human. To become human, is what this individual person, has been created for.” Martin Buber

                              Comment

                              Working...
                              X